856 lines
43 KiB
TeX
856 lines
43 KiB
TeX
\documentclass[letterpaper]{article}
|
|
\author{L.M Goodman}
|
|
\date{August 3, 2014}
|
|
\title{Tezos: A Self-Amending Crypto-Ledger \\ Position Paper}
|
|
\usepackage[utf8]{inputenc}
|
|
|
|
%%\setlength{\parskip}{\baselineskip}
|
|
\usepackage{amsfonts}
|
|
\usepackage{url}
|
|
\usepackage[hidelinks]{hyperref}
|
|
%\usepackage{hyperref}
|
|
\usepackage{listings}
|
|
\usepackage{color}
|
|
\usepackage{epigraph}
|
|
%\epigraphfontsize{\small\itshape}
|
|
\setlength\epigraphwidth{4.6cm}
|
|
\setlength\epigraphrule{0pt}
|
|
|
|
|
|
\begin{document}
|
|
|
|
|
|
\maketitle
|
|
%\epigraphfontsize{\small\itshape}
|
|
|
|
|
|
%\renewcommand{\abstractname}{Introduction}
|
|
|
|
\epigraph{\emph{``Laissez faire les propri\'{e}taires.''}}
|
|
{--- \textup{Pierre-Joseph Proudhon}}
|
|
|
|
\begin{abstract}
|
|
The popularization of Bitcoin, a decentralized crypto-currency has inspired the
|
|
production of several alternative, or ``alt'', currencies. Ethereum, CryptoNote,
|
|
and Zerocash all represent unique contributions to the crypto-currency space.
|
|
Although most alt currencies harbor their own source of innovation, they have
|
|
no means of adopting the innovations of other currencies which may succeed them.
|
|
We aim to remedy the potential for atrophied evolution in the crypto-currency
|
|
space by presenting Tezos, a generic and self-amending crypto-ledger.
|
|
|
|
Tezos can instanciate any blockchain based protocol. Its seed protocol specifies
|
|
a procedure for stakeholders to approve amendments to the protocol,
|
|
\emph{including} amendments to the amendment procedure itself.
|
|
Upgrades to Tezos are staged through a testing environment to allow
|
|
stakeholders to recall potentially problematic amendments.
|
|
|
|
The philosophy of Tezos is inspired by Peter Suber's Nomic\cite{Nomic},
|
|
a game built around a fully introspective set of rules.
|
|
|
|
In this paper, we hope to elucidate the potential benefits of Tezos,
|
|
our choice to implement as a proof-of-stake system, and our choice to write it
|
|
in OCaml.
|
|
|
|
\end{abstract}
|
|
\newpage
|
|
\tableofcontents
|
|
|
|
\section{Motivation}
|
|
In our development of Tezos, we aspire to address four problems we perceive with
|
|
Bitcoin\cite{Bitcoin}:
|
|
\begin{itemize}
|
|
\item[-] The ``hard fork'' problem, or the inability for Bitcoin to dynamically
|
|
innovate due to coordination issues.
|
|
\item[-] Cost and centralization issues raised by Bitcoin's proof-of-work
|
|
system.
|
|
\item[-] The limited expressiveness of Bitcoin's transaction language, which has
|
|
pushed smart contracts onto other chains.
|
|
\item[-] Security concerns regarding the implementation of a crypto-currency.
|
|
\end{itemize}
|
|
|
|
\subsection{The Protocol Fork Problem}
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Keeping Up With Innovation}
|
|
In the wake of Bitcoin's success, many developers and entrepreneurs have
|
|
released alternative crypto-currencies (``altcoins''). While some of these
|
|
altcoins did not diverge dramatically from Bitcoin's original
|
|
code\footnote{wow, such unoriginal}, some presented interesting improvements.
|
|
For example, Litecoin introduced a memory hard proof of work
|
|
function\footnote{scrypt mining ASICs are now available} and a shorter block
|
|
confirmation time. Similarly, Ethereum has designed
|
|
stateful contracts and a Turing-complete transaction language\cite{Ethereum}.
|
|
More important contributions include privacy-preserving ring signatures
|
|
(CryptoNote)\cite{CryptoNote} and untraceable transactions using SNARK
|
|
(Zerocash)\cite{Zerocash}.
|
|
|
|
The rise of altcoins has inspired a vast competition in software innovation.
|
|
Cheerleaders for this Hayekian growth, however, miss a fundamental point: for a
|
|
cryptocurrency to be an effective form of money, it needs to be a stable store
|
|
of value. Innovation within a ledger preserves value through protecting
|
|
the network effect giving the currency its value.
|
|
|
|
To illustrate the problem of many competing altcoins, let us compare a
|
|
crypto-currency and a smart phone. When purchasing a smart phone, the consumer
|
|
is paying for certain features, such as the ability to play music, check email,
|
|
message his friends, and conduct phone calls.
|
|
|
|
Every few weeks, a newer smartphone model is released on the market which often
|
|
contains enhanced features. Though consumers who have the older model may be
|
|
jealous of those with the latest model, the introduction of newer smartphones
|
|
does not render older smartphones dysfunctional.
|
|
|
|
This dynamic would change, however, if the newest phones could not communicate
|
|
with older models. If the many models and styles of smartphone could not be used
|
|
together seamlessly, the value of each smartphone would be reduced to the number
|
|
of people with the same model.
|
|
|
|
Crypto-currencies suffer from the same fate as smartphones which are
|
|
incompatible with one another; they derive their value from a network effect,
|
|
or the number of users who have given it value. To this end, any innovation that
|
|
occurs outside of a crypto-currency will either fail to build enough network
|
|
effect to be noticed, or it will succeed but undermine the value of the savings
|
|
in the old currency. If smartphones were incompatible with older models, there
|
|
would be either very little innovation or extremely disruptive innovation
|
|
forcing older phones into obsolescence.
|
|
|
|
Side-chains are an attempt to allow innovations which will retain
|
|
compatibility with Bitcoin by pegging the value of a new currency to Bitcoin and
|
|
creating a two-way convertibility. Unfortunately, it's unclear whether they
|
|
will be flexible enough to accommodate protocols substantially different fro
|
|
Bitcoin. The only alternative so far is to fork the protocol.
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Economics of Forks}
|
|
|
|
To understand the economics of forks, one must first understand that monetary
|
|
value is primarily a social consensus. It is tempting to equate a
|
|
cryptocurrency with its rules and its ledger, but currencies are actually focal
|
|
points: they draw their value from the common knowledge that they are accepted
|
|
as money. While this may seem circular, there is nothing paradoxical about it.
|
|
From a game theoretic perspective, the perception of a token as a store of value
|
|
is stable so long as it is widespread. Note that, as a ledger, Bitcoin is
|
|
a series of 1s and 0s. The choice to treat the amounts encoded within unspent
|
|
outputs as balances is a purely \emph{social} consensus, not a property of the
|
|
protocol itself.
|
|
|
|
Changes in the protocol are referred to as ``forks''\footnote{not to be confused
|
|
with blockchain forks which happen \emph{within} a protocol}. They are so called
|
|
because, in principle, users have the option to keep using the old protocol.
|
|
Thus, during a fork, the currency splits in two: an old version and a new
|
|
version.
|
|
|
|
A successful fork does not merely require software engineering, but
|
|
the coordination of a critical mass of users. This coordination is hard
|
|
to achieve in practice. Indeed, after a fork, two ledgers exist and users
|
|
are confronted with a dilemma. How should they value each branch of the fork?
|
|
|
|
This is a coordination game where the answer is to primarily value the branch
|
|
other users are expected to primarily value. Of course, said users are likely
|
|
to follow the same strategy and value the branch for the same reason. These
|
|
games were analyzed by economist Thomas Schelling and focal points are
|
|
sometimes referred to as ``Schelling points''\cite{schelling}.
|
|
|
|
Unfortunately, there is no guarantee that this Schelling point will be the most
|
|
desirable choice for the stakeholders, it will merely the ``default'' choice.
|
|
A ``default'' could be to follow the lead of a core development team or the
|
|
decrees of a government regardless of their merit.
|
|
|
|
An attacker capable of changing social consensus
|
|
controls the currency for all intents and purposes.
|
|
The option to stick with the original protocol is widely irrelevant
|
|
if the value of its tokens is annihilated by a consensus shift.%
|
|
\footnote{The argument that there can never be more than 21 million bitcoin
|
|
because ``if a fork raised the cap, then it wouldn't be Bitcoin anymore''
|
|
isn't very substantive, for Bitcoin is what the consensus says it is.}
|
|
|
|
Core development teams are a potentially a dangerous source of centralization.
|
|
Though users can fork any open source project,
|
|
that ability offers no protection against an attacker
|
|
with enough clout to alter the social consensus.
|
|
Even assuming the likely benevolence of a core development team,
|
|
it represents a weak point on which an attacker could exercise leverage.
|
|
|
|
Tezos guards against the vulnerabilities wrought by the source of centralization
|
|
through radically decentralized protocol forks.
|
|
It uses its own cryptoledger to let stakeholders coordinate on forks.
|
|
This allows coordination and enshrines the principle that
|
|
forks are not valid unless they are endogenous,
|
|
making it much harder to attack the protocol by moving the consensus.
|
|
|
|
Suppose for instance that a popular developer announces his intention to fork
|
|
Tezos without making use of the protocol's internal procedure. ``Why would he
|
|
attempt to bypass this process?'' might ask stakeholders. Most certainly,
|
|
because he knew that he wouldn't be able to build consensus around his proposed
|
|
fork \emph{within} Tezos.
|
|
|
|
This signals to the stakeholders that their preferred consensus would be to
|
|
reject this fork, and the Schelling point is thus to refuse it, no matter the
|
|
clout of that developer.
|
|
|
|
|
|
\subsection{Shortcomings of Proof-of-Work}
|
|
|
|
The proof-of-work mechanism used by Bitcoin is a careful balance
|
|
of incentives meant to prevent the double spending problem.
|
|
While it has nice theoretical properties in the absence of miner
|
|
collusion, it suffers in practice from severe shortcomings.
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Mining Power Concentration}
|
|
There are several problems with proof-of-work as a foundation for
|
|
crypto-currencies. The most salient problem, which is all too relevant
|
|
as of 2014, is the existence of centralized mining pools, which concentrate
|
|
power in the hands of a few individuals.
|
|
|
|
The proof-of-work mechanism is decentralized, which means that users do not
|
|
need to \emph{explicitely} trust anyone to secure the currency. However,
|
|
\emph{implicitely}, Bitcoin has yielded a system where all users have to trust
|
|
the benevolence of one or two pool operators to secure the currency.
|
|
|
|
A conspiracy of miners holding more than 50\% of the hashing power
|
|
is known as 51\% attack\cite{51pct}. It allows the attackers
|
|
to prevent transactions from being made, to undo transactions,
|
|
to steal recently minted coins and to to double spend\cite{centralized}.
|
|
|
|
A centralized mint signing blocks would be just as secure,
|
|
and far less wasteful, as a miner controlling 51\% of the hashing power.
|
|
If a centralized mint is unacceptable to Bitcoin users,
|
|
they should not tolerate \textit{de facto} centralization of mining power.
|
|
|
|
The concentration of mining power is no coincidence:
|
|
large mining pools face less variance in their returns than their competitors
|
|
and can thus afford to grow their operation more.
|
|
In turn, this growth increases their market share and lowers their variance.
|
|
|
|
To make things worse, the large mining pool ghash.io
|
|
has hinted at a business model where they would prioritize ``premium''
|
|
transactions submitted directly to them. This means that large miners would earn
|
|
proportionally more than smaller miners. Sadly, p2pool has had trouble
|
|
attracting hashing power as most miners selfishly prefer the convenience of
|
|
centralized mining-pools.
|
|
|
|
Many have argued that fears of market concentration are
|
|
overblown. They are generalizing hastily from the real world economy.
|
|
Real businesses compete in a rapidly changing landscape
|
|
where Schumpeterian creative destruction exercises
|
|
constant evolutionary pressure on incumbents.
|
|
Real businesses need local knowledge, face organizational issues
|
|
and principal agent problems. Bitcoin mining is a purely synthetic economic
|
|
sector centered around hashing power, a purely fungible commodity.
|
|
It would be mistaken to hastily generalize and think that such a sterile
|
|
environment is endowed with the same organic robustness that characterizes a
|
|
complex, fertile, economy.\footnote{It is possible that a new technology
|
|
will supplant ASICs who themselves replaced FPGA boards. However, the pace of
|
|
this type of innovation is nowhere fast enough to prevent miners from forming
|
|
dominating positions for long period of times; and such innovation would benefit
|
|
but a new (or the same) small clique of people who initially possess the new
|
|
technology or eventually amass the capital to repeat the same pattern.}
|
|
|
|
Furthermore, the economic argument generally holds that natural monopolies have
|
|
few incentives to abuse their position. The same could be said about a Bitcoin
|
|
miner --- after all, why would a dominant miner destroy the value of their
|
|
investments by compromising the currency?
|
|
Unfortunately, this still creates a huge systemic risk as such miners can be
|
|
compromised by a dishonest attacker. The cost of executing a double spending
|
|
attack against the network is \emph{no more} than the cost of subverting a few
|
|
large mining pool.
|
|
|
|
There have been proposals intended to address this issue by tweaking the
|
|
protocol so it would be impossible for pool organizers to trust their members
|
|
not to cheat. However, these proposals only prevent pools from gathering mining
|
|
force from anonymous participants with whom there is no possibility of
|
|
retaliation. Pooling is still possible between non-anonymous people:
|
|
organizers may operate all the mining hardware while participants hold shares,
|
|
or organizers may track cheaters by requiring inclusion of an identifying nonce
|
|
in the blocks they are supposed to hash. The result of such proposals would thus
|
|
be to increase variance for anonymous mining operations and to push towards
|
|
further concentration in the hands of mining cartels.
|
|
|
|
Proof-of-stake, as used by Tezos, does not suffer from this problem:
|
|
inasmuch as it is possible to hold 51\% of the mining power,
|
|
this implies holding 51\% of the currency,
|
|
which is not only much more onerous than controlling 51\% of hashing power but
|
|
implies fundamentally better \emph{incentives}.
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Bad incentives}
|
|
There is an even deeper problem with proof-of-work, one that is much harder to
|
|
mitigate than the concentration of mining power: a misalignment of incentives
|
|
between miners and stakeholders.
|
|
|
|
Indeed, in the long run, the total mining revenues will be the sum of the all
|
|
transaction fees paid to the miners. Since miners compete to produce hashes,
|
|
the amount of money spent on mining will be slightly smaller than the revenues.
|
|
In turn, the amount spent on transactions depends on the supply and demand for
|
|
transactions. The supply of transactions on the blockchain is determined by the
|
|
block size and is fixed.
|
|
|
|
Unfortunately, there is reason to expect that the demand for transactions will
|
|
fall to very low levels. People are likely to make use of off-chain transaction
|
|
mechanisms via trusted third parties, particularly for small amounts, in order
|
|
to alleviate the need to wait for confirmations. Payment processors may only
|
|
need to clear with each other infrequently.
|
|
|
|
This scenario is not only economically likely, it seems necessary given the
|
|
relatively low transaction rate supported by Bitcoin. Since blockchain
|
|
transaction will have to compete with off-chain transaction, the amount spent on
|
|
transactions will approach its cost, which, given modern infrastructure, should
|
|
be close to zero.
|
|
|
|
Attempting to impose minimum transaction fees may only exacerbate the problem
|
|
and cause users to rely on off-chain transaction more. As the amount paid in
|
|
transaction fees collapses, so will the miner's revenues, and so will the cost
|
|
of executing a 51\% attack. To put it in a nutshell, the security of a
|
|
proof-of-work blockchain suffers from a commons problem\cite{btccommons}.
|
|
Core developer Mike Hearn has suggested the use of special transactions to
|
|
subsidize mining using a pledge type of fund raising\cite{dominantassurance}.
|
|
A robust currency should not need to rely on charity to operate securely.
|
|
|
|
Proof-of-stake fixes these bad incentives by aligning the incentives of the
|
|
miners and stakeholders: by very definition, the miners \emph{are} the
|
|
stakeholders, and are thus interested in keeping the transaction costs low.
|
|
At the same time, because proof-of-stake mining is not based on destruction of
|
|
resources, the transaction cost (whether direct fees or indirect inflation)
|
|
are entirely captured by miners, who can cover their operating costs
|
|
without having to compete through wealth destruction.
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Cost}
|
|
An alternative is to keep permanent mining rewards, as Dogecoin\cite{doge} has
|
|
considered. Unfortunately, proof-of-work arbitrarily increases the costs to the
|
|
users without increasing the profits of the miners, incurring a deadweight loss.
|
|
Indeed, since miners compete to produce hashes, the amount of money they spend
|
|
on mining will be slightly smaller than the revenues, and in the long run,
|
|
the profits they make will be commensurate with the value of their transaction
|
|
services, while the cost of mining is lost to everyone.
|
|
|
|
This is not simply a nominal effect: real economic goods (time in fabs,
|
|
electricity, engineering efforts) are being removed from the economy for the
|
|
sake of proof-of-work mining. As of June 2014, Bitcoin's annual inflation stands
|
|
at a little over 10\% and about \$2.16M dollars are being burned daily for the
|
|
sake of maintaining a system that provides little to no security over a
|
|
centralized system in the hands of ghash.io.
|
|
|
|
The very security of a proof-of-work scheme rests on this actual cost being
|
|
higher than what an attacker is willing to pay, which is bound to increase
|
|
with the success of the currency.
|
|
|
|
Proof-of-stake eliminates this source of waste without lowering the cost of
|
|
attacks --- indeed, it automatically scales up the cost of an attack as the
|
|
currency appreciates. Because the thing you must prove to mine is not
|
|
destruction of existing resources but provision of existing resources,
|
|
a proof-of-stake currency does not rely on destroying massive resources
|
|
as it gains in popularity.
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Control}
|
|
Last but not least, the proof-of-work system puts the miners,
|
|
not the stakeholders, in charge. Forks for instance require the consent of a
|
|
majority of the miners. This poses a potential conflict of interest: a majority
|
|
of miners could decide to hold the blockchain hostage until stakeholders consent
|
|
to a protocol fork increasing the mining rewards; more generally, they will hold
|
|
onto the hugely wasteful system that empowers them longer than is economically
|
|
beneficial for users.
|
|
|
|
\subsection{Smart Contracts}
|
|
Though Bitcoin does allow for smart contracts, most of its opcodes
|
|
have been historically disabled and the possibilities are limited.
|
|
Ethereum introduced a smart contract system with some critical differences:
|
|
their scripting language is Turing complete and they substitute
|
|
stateful accounts to Bitcoin's unspent outputs.
|
|
|
|
While emphasis has been put on the Turing complete aspect of the language,
|
|
the second property is by far the most interesting and powerful of the two.
|
|
In Bitcoin, an output can be thought of as having only two states: spent and
|
|
unspent. In Ethereum, accounts (protected by a key) hold a balance, a contract
|
|
code and a data store. The state of an account's storage can be mutated
|
|
by making a transaction towards this account. The transaction specifies an
|
|
amount and the parameters passed to the contract code.
|
|
|
|
A downside of a Turing complete scripting language for the contracts
|
|
is that the number of steps needed to execute a script is potentially unbounded,
|
|
a property which is generally uncomputable.
|
|
|
|
To address this problem, Ethereum has devised a system by which the miner
|
|
validating the transaction requires a fee proportional to the complexity
|
|
and number of steps needed to execute the contract.
|
|
|
|
Yet, for the blockchain to be secure, \emph{all} the active nodes need to
|
|
validate the transaction. A malicious miner could include in his block a
|
|
transaction that he crafted specially to run into an infinite loop and pay
|
|
himself an exorbitant fee for validating this transaction. Other miners could
|
|
waste a very long time validating this transaction. Worse, they could just
|
|
slack and fail to validate it. In practice though, most of the interesting
|
|
smart contracts can be implemented with very simple business logic and do not
|
|
need to perform complex calculations.
|
|
|
|
Our solution is to cap the maximum number of steps that a program is allowed to
|
|
run for in a single transaction. Since blocks have a size limit that caps the
|
|
number of transactions per block, there is also a cap on the number of
|
|
computation steps per block. This rate limitation foils CPU-usage
|
|
denial-of-service attacks. Meanwhile, legitimate users can issue multiple
|
|
transactions to compute more steps than allowed in a single transaction,
|
|
though at a limited rate. Miners may decide to exclude too long of an execution
|
|
if they feel the included fee is too small. Since the Tezos protocol is
|
|
amendable, the cap can be increased in future revisions and new cryptographic
|
|
primitives included in the scripting language as the need develops.
|
|
|
|
\subsection{Correctness}
|
|
Bitcoin underpins a \$8B valuation with a modest code base. As security
|
|
researcher Dan Kaminsky explains, Bitcoin looks like a security nightmare on
|
|
paper. A \verb!C++! code base with a custom binary protocol powers nodes
|
|
connected to the Internet while holding e-cash, sounds like a recipe for
|
|
disaster. \verb!C++! programs are often riddled with memory corruption bugs.
|
|
When they are connecting to the Internet, this creates vulnerabilities
|
|
exploitable by remote attackers. E-cash gives an immediate payoff to any
|
|
attacker clever enough to discover and exploit such a vulnerability.
|
|
|
|
Fortunately, Bitcoin's implementation has proven very resilient to attacks
|
|
thus far, with some exceptions. In August 2010, a bug where the sum of two
|
|
outputs overflowed to a negative number allowed attackers to create two
|
|
outputs of $92233720368.54$ coins from an input of $0.50$ coins.
|
|
More recently, massive vulnerabilities such as the heartbleed bug
|
|
have been discovered in the OpenSSL libraries. These vulnerabilities have
|
|
one thing in common, they happened because languages like \verb!C! and
|
|
\verb!C++! do not perform any checks on the operations they perform. For the
|
|
sake of efficiency, they may access random parts of the memory, add integers
|
|
larger than natively supported, etc. While these vulnerabilities have spared
|
|
Bitcoin, they do no not bode well for the security of the system.
|
|
|
|
Other languages do not exhibit those problems. OCaml is a functional programming
|
|
language developed by the INRIA since 1996 (and itself based on earlier
|
|
efforts). Its speed is comparable to that of \verb!C++! and it generally
|
|
features among the fastest programming languages in benchmarks\cite{shootout}.
|
|
More importantly, OCaml is strongly typed and offers a powerful type inference
|
|
system. Its expressive syntax and semantics, including powerful pattern matching
|
|
and higher-order modules, make it easy to concisely and correctly describe the
|
|
type of logic underpinning blockchain based protocols.
|
|
|
|
OCaml's semantic is fairly rigorous and a very large subset has been
|
|
formalized\cite{semantic}, which removes any ambiguity as to what is the
|
|
intended behavior of amendments.
|
|
|
|
In addition, Coq, one of the most advanced proof checking software
|
|
is able to extract OCaml code from proofs. As Tezos matures, it will be
|
|
possible to automatically extract key parts of the protocol's code from
|
|
mathematical proofs of correctness.
|
|
|
|
Examples of spectacular software failure abound. The heartbleed bug caused
|
|
millions of dollars in damages. In 2013, a single bug at high-frequency trading
|
|
firm Knight capital caused half a billion dollars worth of losses. In 1996, an
|
|
arithmetic overflow bug caused the crash of Ariane 5, a rocket that had cost
|
|
\$7B to develop; the cost of the rocket and the cargo was estimated at \$500M.
|
|
|
|
All of these bugs could have been prevented with the use of formal verification.
|
|
Formal verification has progressed by leaps and bounds in recent years,
|
|
it is time to use it in real systems.
|
|
|
|
\section{Abstract Blockchains}
|
|
|
|
Tezos attempts to represent a blockchain protocol in the most general way
|
|
possible while attempting to remain as efficient as a native protocol.
|
|
The goal of a blockchain is to represent a single state being concurrently
|
|
edited. In order to avoid conflicts between concurrent edits, it represents the
|
|
state as a ledger, that is as a series of transformations applied to an initial
|
|
state. These transformations are the ``blocks'' of the blockchain, and --- in
|
|
the case of Bitcoin --- the state is mostly the set of unspent outputs. Since
|
|
the blocks are created asynchronously by many concurrent nodes, a block tree is
|
|
formed. Each leaf of the tree represents a possible state and the end of a
|
|
different blockchain. Bitcoin specifies that only one branch should be
|
|
considered the valid branch: the one with the greatest total difficulty.
|
|
Blocks, as their name suggests, actually bundle together
|
|
multiple operations (known as transactions in the case of Bitcoin).
|
|
These operations are sequentially applied to the state.
|
|
|
|
\subsection{Three Protocols}
|
|
|
|
It is important to distinguish three protocols in cryptoledgers:
|
|
the network protocol, the transaction protocol, and the consensus protocol.
|
|
|
|
The role of the meta shell is to handle the network protocol
|
|
in as agnostic a way as possible while delegating the transaction and consensus
|
|
protocol to an abstracted implementation.
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Network Protocol}
|
|
|
|
The network protocol in Bitcoin is essentially the gossip network that allows
|
|
the broadcasting of transactions, the downloading and publishing of blocks,
|
|
the discovery of peers, etc. It is where most development occurs. For instance,
|
|
bloom filters were introduced in 2012 through BIP0037 to speed up the simple
|
|
payment verification for clients which do not download the whole blockchain.
|
|
|
|
Changes to the network protocol are relatively uncontroversial. There
|
|
may be initial disagreements on the desirability of these changes, but all
|
|
parties interests are fundamentally aligned overall.
|
|
|
|
These changes do not need to happen in concert either. One could devise a way to
|
|
integrate Bitcoin transactions steganographically into pictures of cats posted
|
|
on the Internet. If enough people started publishing transactions this way,
|
|
miners would start parsing cat pictures to find transactions to include in the
|
|
blockchain.
|
|
|
|
While a healthy network requires compatibility, competing innovation in the
|
|
network protocol generally strengthens a cryptocurrency.
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Transaction Protocol}
|
|
The transaction protocol describes what makes transactions valid. It is defined
|
|
in Bitcoin, for instance, through a scripting language. First, coins are created
|
|
by miners when they find a block. The miner then attaches a script to the coins
|
|
that he mined.
|
|
|
|
Such a script is known as an ``unspent output''. Transactions combine outputs
|
|
by providing arguments for which their scripts evaluate to true. These arguments
|
|
can be thought of keys and the scripts as padlocks.
|
|
|
|
In simple transactions, such scripts are merely signature-checking scripts but
|
|
more complex scripts can be formed. These outputs are added up and allocated
|
|
among a set of new outputs. If the amount of output spent is greater than the
|
|
amount allocated, the difference can be claimed by the miner.
|
|
|
|
Changes to the transaction protocol are more controversial than changes to
|
|
the network protocol. While a small group of people could unilaterally start
|
|
using the cat-picture broadcast algorithm, changing the transaction protocol
|
|
is trickier. Such changes typically do not affect the block validity
|
|
and thus only require the cooperation of a majority of the miners.
|
|
These are generally referred to as ``soft-fork''.
|
|
|
|
Some relatively uncontroversial changes still stand a chance to be implemented
|
|
there. For instance a fix to the transaction malleability issue would be a
|
|
transaction protocol level change. The introduction of Zerocash, also a
|
|
transaction protocol level change, risks being too controversial to be
|
|
undertaken.
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Consensus Protocol}
|
|
The consensus protocol of Bitcoin describes the way consensus is built
|
|
around the most difficult chain and the miner reward schedules.
|
|
It allows miners to draw transactions from the coin base,
|
|
it dictates how difficulty changes over time,
|
|
it indicates which blocks are valid
|
|
and which are part of the ``official'' chain.
|
|
|
|
This is by far the most central and most difficult to change protocol,
|
|
often requiring a ``hard-fork'', that is a fork invalidating old blocks.
|
|
For instance, the proof of work system, as is the reliance on SHA256 as a
|
|
proof-of-work system, etc.
|
|
|
|
\subsection{Network Shell}
|
|
Tezos separates those three protocols.
|
|
The transaction protocol and the consensus protocol
|
|
are implemented in an isolated module plugged
|
|
into a generic network shell responsible for maintaining the blockchain.
|
|
|
|
In order for the protocol to remain generic, we define the following interface.
|
|
We want our blockchain to represent the current ``state'' of the economy,
|
|
which we call in Tezos the \textbf{Context}.
|
|
This could include the balances of the various accounts
|
|
and other informations such as the current block number.
|
|
Blocks are seen as operators that transform an old state into a new state.
|
|
|
|
In this respect, a protocol can be described by only two functions:
|
|
\begin{itemize}
|
|
\item[-] \textbf{apply} which takes a Context and a block and returns
|
|
either a valid Context or an invalid result (should the block be invalid)
|
|
\item[-] \textbf{score} which takes a Context and returns a score
|
|
allowing us to compare various leafs of the blockchain
|
|
to determine the canonical one.
|
|
In Bitcoin, we would simply record the total difficulty
|
|
or the chain inside the Context and return this value.
|
|
\end{itemize}
|
|
|
|
Strikingly, these two functions alone can implement \emph{any} blockchain based
|
|
crypto-ledger. In addition, we attach those functions to the context itself
|
|
and expose the following two functions to the protocol:
|
|
|
|
\begin{itemize}
|
|
\item[-] \textbf{set\_test\_protocol} which replaces the protocol used in the
|
|
test-net with a new protocol (typically one that has been adopted through a
|
|
stakeholder voter).
|
|
\item[-] \textbf{promote\_test\_protocol} which replaces the current protocol
|
|
with the protocol currently being tested
|
|
\end{itemize}
|
|
|
|
These two procedures allow the protocol to validate its own replacement.
|
|
While the seed protocol relies on a simple super-majority rule with a quorum,
|
|
more complex rules can be adopted in the future.
|
|
For instance, the stakeholders could vote
|
|
to require certain properties to be respected by any future protocol.
|
|
This could be achieved by integrating a proof checker within the protocol
|
|
and requiring that every amendment include a proof of constitutionality.
|
|
|
|
\section{Proof-of-Stake}
|
|
Tezos can implement any type of blockchain algorithm:
|
|
proof-of-work, proof-of-stake, or even centralized.
|
|
Due to the shortcomings of the proof-of-work mechanism,
|
|
the Tezos seed protocol implements a proof-of-stake system.
|
|
There are considerable theoretical hurdles to designing a working
|
|
proof-of-stake systems, we will explain our way of dealing with
|
|
them.\footnote{A full, technical, description of our proof-of-stake system is
|
|
given in the Tezos white paper.}
|
|
|
|
\subsection{Is Proof-of-Stake Impossible?}
|
|
|
|
There are very serious theoretical hurdles to any proof-of-stake system.
|
|
The main argument against the very possibility of a proof-of-stake system
|
|
is the following:
|
|
a new user downloads a client and connects for the first time to the network.
|
|
He receives a tree of blocks with two larges branches
|
|
starting from the genesis hash.
|
|
Both branches display a thriving economic activity,
|
|
but they represent two fundamentally different histories.
|
|
One has clearly been crafted by an attacker, but which one is the real chain?
|
|
|
|
In the case of Bitcoin, the canonical blockchain is the one representing the
|
|
largest amount of work. This does not mean that rewriting history is impossible,
|
|
but it is costly to do so, especially as one's hashing power could be used
|
|
towards mining blocks on the real blockchain.
|
|
In a proof-of-stake system where blocks are signed by stakeholders,
|
|
a former stakeholder (who has since cashed out) could use his old signatures
|
|
to costlessly fork the blockchain
|
|
--- this is known as the nothing-at-stake problem.
|
|
|
|
|
|
\subsection{Mitigations}
|
|
|
|
While this theoretical objection seems ironclad, there are effective mitigations.
|
|
An important insight is to consider that there are roughly two kind of forks:
|
|
very deep ones that rewrite a substantial fraction of the history
|
|
and short ones that attempt to double spend.
|
|
On the surface there is only a quantitative difference between the two
|
|
but in practice the incentives, motivations,
|
|
and mitigation strategies are different.
|
|
|
|
No system is unconditionally safe, not Bitcoin, not even public key
|
|
cryptography. Systems are designed to be safe for a given \emph{threat model}. How well
|
|
that model captures reality is, \emph{in fine}, an empirical question.
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Checkpoints}
|
|
Occasional checkpoints can be an effective way to prevent very long blockchain reorganizations.
|
|
Checkpoints are a hack. As Ben Laurie points out, Bitcoin's use of checkpoints
|
|
taints its status as a fully decentralized currency\cite{distrib_impossible}.
|
|
|
|
Yet, in practice, annual or even semi-annual checkpoints hardly seem problematic.
|
|
Forming a consensus over a single hash value over a period of months is
|
|
something that human institutions are perfectly capable of safely accomplishing.
|
|
This hash can be published in major newspapers around the world,
|
|
carved on the tables of freshmen students, spray painted under bridges,
|
|
included in songs, impressed on fresh concrete, tattooed on pet ferrets...
|
|
there are countless ways to record occasional checkpoints
|
|
in a way that makes forgery impossible.
|
|
In contrast, the problem of forming a consensus over a period of minutes
|
|
is more safely solved by a decentralized protocol.
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Statistical Detection}
|
|
Transactions can reference blocks belonging to the canonical blockchain,
|
|
thus implicitely signing the chain. An attacker attempting to forge a
|
|
long reorganization can only produce transactions involving coins he
|
|
controlled as off the last checkpoint. A long, legitimate, chain would
|
|
typically show activity in a larger fraction of the coins and can thus
|
|
be distinguished, statistically, from the forgery.
|
|
|
|
This family of techniques (often called TAPOS, for
|
|
``transactions as proof of stake'') does not work well for short forks where the sample
|
|
is too small to perform a reliable statistical test. However, they can be combined
|
|
with a technique dealing with short term forks to form a composite selection
|
|
algorithm robust to both type of forks.
|
|
|
|
%% \paragraph{Cementing}
|
|
%% Cementing --- a technique which consists in refusing to
|
|
%% consider and relay blocks causing medium to large reorganizations ---
|
|
%% can be quite effective.
|
|
%% The main theoretical weakness of cementing is that
|
|
%% it prevents a node from ever converging to the right blockchain
|
|
%% if it first accepts the wrong fork.
|
|
%% However, this requires the ability to isolate a node on the network.
|
|
%% Given this ability, it is possible to trick the node into accepting
|
|
%% a transaction that will be double spent on the main chain ---
|
|
%% this is true of Bitcoin and almost all blockchain based systems.
|
|
%% Such attacks can generally be detected statistically.
|
|
%% If the attack is detected, it suffices to stop accepting payments and to deactivate cementing
|
|
%% until convergence with the main chain has been achieved.
|
|
%% In the case of a new node bootstrapping on the network,
|
|
%% the cementing can be activated once the user is convinced
|
|
%% that his client has found the main chain (either by waiting long enough
|
|
%% or by requesting hashes from a few trusted sources).
|
|
%% Note that this bootstrapping procedure does not involve any more trust
|
|
%% or centralization than is already involved
|
|
%% in the process of merely downloading the client.
|
|
|
|
\subsection{The Nothing-At-Stake Problem}
|
|
An interesting approach to solving the nothing-at-stake problem was
|
|
outlined by Vitalik Buterin in the algorithm Slasher\cite{Slasher}.
|
|
However, Slasher still relies on a proof of work mechanism to mine blocks
|
|
and assumes a bound on the length of feasible forks.
|
|
|
|
We retain the main idea which consists in punishing double signers.
|
|
If signing rewards are delayed, they can be withheld
|
|
if any attempt at double spending is detected.
|
|
This is enough to prevent a selfish stakeholder
|
|
from opportunistically attempting to sign a fork
|
|
for the sake of collecting a reward should the fork succeed.
|
|
However, once rewards have been paid,
|
|
this incentive to behave honestly disappears;
|
|
thus, we use a delay long enough for TAPOS to become
|
|
statistically significant or for checkpointing to take place.
|
|
|
|
In order to incentivize stakeholders to behave honestly,
|
|
we introduce a ticker system. A prospective miner must
|
|
burn a certain amount of coins in order to exercise his
|
|
mining right. This amount is automatically returned to
|
|
him if he fails to mine, or after a long delay.
|
|
|
|
In order to allow stakeholders not to be permanently connected
|
|
to the Internet and not to expose private keys, a different,
|
|
signature key is used.
|
|
|
|
\subsection{Threat Models}
|
|
No system is unconditionally safe, not Bitcoin, not even public key
|
|
cryptography. Systems are designed to be safe for a given \emph{threat model}. How well
|
|
that model captures reality is, \emph{in fine}, an empirical question.
|
|
|
|
Bitcoin does offer an interesting guarantee: it attempts to tolerate amoral
|
|
but selfish participants. As long as miners do not collude, it is not necessary
|
|
to assume that any participant is honest, merely than they prefer making money
|
|
to destroying the network. However, non collusion, a key condition, is too
|
|
often forgotten, and the claim of Bitcoin's
|
|
``trustlessness'' is zealously repeated without much thought.
|
|
|
|
With checkpointing (be it yearly), the same properties can be achieved by
|
|
a proof-of-stake system.
|
|
|
|
Without checkpointing proof-of-stake systems cannot make this claim. Indeed,
|
|
it would be theoretically possible for an attacker to purchase old keys from
|
|
a large number of former stakeholders, with no consequence to them. In this case,
|
|
a stronger assumption is needed about participants, namely that a majority of current or
|
|
former stakeholders cannot be cheaply corrupted into participating in an
|
|
attack on the network. In this case, the role ``stake'' in the proof-of-stake is
|
|
only to avoid adverse selection by malicious actors in the consensus group.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
\section{Potential Developments}
|
|
|
|
In this section, we explore some ideas
|
|
that we're specifically interested in integrating to the Tezos protocol.
|
|
|
|
\subsection{Privacy Preserving Transactions}
|
|
One of the most pressing protocol updates will be
|
|
the introduction of privacy preserving transactions.
|
|
We know of two ways to achieve this:
|
|
ring signatures and non-interactive zero-knowledge proofs of knowledge
|
|
(NIZKPK).
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Ring Signatures}
|
|
CryptoNote has built a protocol using ring signatures to preserve privacy.
|
|
Users are able to spend coins
|
|
without revealing which of $N$ addresses spent the coins.
|
|
Double spenders are revealed and the transaction deemed invalid.
|
|
This works similarly to the coin-join protocol
|
|
\emph{without} requiring the cooperation of the addresses involved in
|
|
obfuscating the transaction.
|
|
|
|
One of the main advantage of ring signatures is that they are comparatively
|
|
simpler to implement than NIZKPK and rely on more mature cryptographic
|
|
primitives which have stood the test of time.
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Non Interactive Zero-knowledge Proofs of Knowledge}
|
|
Matthew Green et al. proposed the use of NIZKPK
|
|
to achieve transaction untraceability in a blockchain based cryptocurrency.
|
|
The latest proposition, Zerocash, maintains
|
|
a set of coins with attached secrets in a Merkle tree.
|
|
Committed coins are redeemed by providing a NIZKPK
|
|
of the secret attached to a coin in the tree.
|
|
It uses a relatively new primitive, SNARKs,
|
|
to build very small proofs which can be efficiently checked.
|
|
|
|
This technique is attractive but suffers from drawbacks.
|
|
The cryptographic primitives involved are fairly new
|
|
and have not been scrutinized as heavily
|
|
as the relatively simple elliptic curve cryptography involved in Bitcoin.
|
|
|
|
Secondly, the construction of these proofs relies on the CRS model.
|
|
This effectively means that a trusted setup is required,
|
|
though the use of secure multi-party computation
|
|
can reduce the risk that such a setup be compromised.
|
|
|
|
\subsection{Amendment Rules}
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Constitutionalism}
|
|
|
|
While this is more advanced, it is possible to integrate a proof checker
|
|
within the protocol so that only amendments carrying a formal proof that
|
|
they respect particular properties can be adopted. In effect this enforces
|
|
a form of constitutionality.
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Futarchy}
|
|
Robin Hanson has proposed that we vote on values and bet on beliefs.
|
|
He calls such a system ``Futarchy''\cite{Futarchy}. The main idea
|
|
is that values are best captured by a majoritarian consensus while the choice
|
|
of policies conducive to realizing those values is best left to a prediction
|
|
market.
|
|
|
|
This system can quite litteraly be implemented in Tezos. Stakeholders would
|
|
first vote on a trusted datafeed representing the satisfaction of a value.
|
|
This might be for example the exchange rate of coins against a basket
|
|
of international currencies. An internal prediction market would be formed
|
|
to estimate the change in this indicator conditional on various code
|
|
amendments being adopted. The market-making in those contracts can be
|
|
subsidized by issuing coins to market makers in order to improve price discovery
|
|
and liquidity. In the end, the amendment deemed most likely to improve the
|
|
indicator would be automatically adopted.
|
|
|
|
\subsection{Solving Collective Action Problems}
|
|
The collective action problem arises when multiple parties would benefit from
|
|
taking an action but none benefit from individually undertaking the action.
|
|
This is also known as the free-rider problem.
|
|
There are several actions that the holders of a cryptocurrency could undertake
|
|
to raise its profile or defend it against legal challenges.
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Raising Awareness}
|
|
|
|
As of July 2014, the market capitalization of Bitcoin was around \$8B.
|
|
By spending about 0.05\% of the Bitcoin monetary mass every month,
|
|
Bitcoin could make highly visible
|
|
charitable donations of \$1M \emph{every single week}.
|
|
Would, as of 2014, an entire year of weekly charitable donations
|
|
raise the value of Bitcoin by more than 0.6\%?
|
|
We think the answer is clearly, and resoundingly ``yes''.
|
|
Bitcoin stakeholders would be doing well while doing good.
|
|
|
|
However, Bitcoin stakeholders are unable to undertake such an operation
|
|
because of the difficulty of forming large binding contracts. This type
|
|
of collective action problem is solved in Tezos.
|
|
A protocol amendment can set up a procedure by which
|
|
stakeholders may vote every month on a few addresses
|
|
where 0.05\% of the monetary mass would be spent.
|
|
The stakeholder's consensus might be to avoid dilution
|
|
by voting on an invalid address,
|
|
but it could also be that the money would be better spent as a charitable gift.
|
|
|
|
\subsubsection{Funding Innovation}
|
|
|
|
Financing of innovation would also be facilitated
|
|
by incorporating bounties directly within the protocol.
|
|
A protocol could define unit tests and automatically award a reward
|
|
to any code proposal that passes these tests.
|
|
|
|
Conversely, an innovator designing a new protocol
|
|
could include a reward to himself within the protocol.
|
|
While his protocol could be copied and the reward stripped,
|
|
the stakeholder's consensus would likely be to reward the original creator.
|
|
Stakeholders are playing a repeated game
|
|
and it would be foolish to defect by refusing a reasonable reward.
|
|
|
|
|
|
\section*{Conclusion}
|
|
|
|
We've presented issues with the existing cryptocurrencies
|
|
and offered Tezos as a solution.
|
|
While the irony of preventing the fragmentation of cryptocurrencies
|
|
by releasing a new one does not escape us,%\cite{xkcd_standards}
|
|
Tezos truly aims to be the \emph{last} cryptocurrency.
|
|
|
|
No matter what innovations other protocols produce,
|
|
it will be possible for Tezos stakeholders to adopt these innovations.
|
|
Furthermore, the ability to solve collective action problems
|
|
and easily implement protocols in OCaml will make Tezos one of the most reactive cryptocurrency.
|
|
|
|
\bibliographystyle{unsrt}
|
|
\bibliography{biblio}
|
|
|
|
\end{document}
|